Karachi +92 300 2224351,Lahore 0321 8498708
Karachi: mty.park@uosl.com.pk Lahore: lahore.depo@uosl-lhr.com (NTN # 4120586-3)

Asset Pricing and Portfolio Choice Theory

This shows that asymmetric information can give rise to momentum in a dynamic noisy rational expectations equilibrium. Otherwise stated, outperformance of the index by the momentum portfolio should not be viewed as evidence of deviation from rational expectations. It should be noted, however, that in the other equilibria we simulated, the momentum portfolio did not outperform the index. Thus the excess performance of the momentum portfolio is not a robust feature of our equilibria, in contrast with the excess performance of the price-contingent portfolio. The corollary states that equilibrium returns will be positively correlated too.

6 compares the performance of the price-contingent, size, value, and momentum portfolios. We plot the evolution of the wealth of an investor starting on June 30, 1932, with $1 and investing according to one of five possible strategies. The five strategies were constructed to have the same ex post monthly return volatility over the period of July 1932 to December 2000. Hence, the ordering in mean–variance space can be readily inferred from the relative wealth levels that the strategies generate. 30 Analogously, the value strategy exploits the difference between the returns of firms with high book value of equity relative to market value and firms with low book-to-market ratio.

Each chapter includes a Notes and References section providing additional pathways to the literature. Each chapter includes a ”Notes and References” section providing additional pathways to the literature. Each chapter includes a “Notes and References” section providing additional pathways to the literature. This book is intended as a textbook for asset pricing theory courses at the Ph.D. or Masters in Quantitative Finance level and as a reference for financial researchers. The first two parts of the book explain portfolio choice and asset pricing theory in single‐period, discrete‐time, and continuous‐time models.

36 Our estimation of the correlation between returns and prices is based on simple linear GLS. We did not investigate more sophisticated specifications or estimation strategies, such as nonlinear least squares or conditional heteroscedasticity. No attempt was made to estimate the optimal window size on which to estimate the correlation between prices and returns. Refining the statistical analysis along those and other lines may yield more powerful information extraction and consequently superior performance. Our portfolio allocation strategy will be based on projections of a month’s returns onto the vector of relative prices at the beginning of the month.

We estimate the volatility of the index as the mean squared difference between its return and that predicted by the GLS regression. The difference between the Sharpe ratios of the two portfolios is estimated as the difference between the two average returns, divided by the volatility of the index. We use the same denominator for the two Sharpe ratios, since the price-contingent strategy is constructed to have the same volatility as the index. 19 We use the returns that are adjusted for the substantial transaction costs caused by flows of individual assets in and out of the portfolios. Such flows are the result of changes in firm size, book, and market values.

2 Analysis

Compared to the portfolio of aggregate risks, uninformed agents invest more in assets about which they are more optimistic than the informed agents. To cope with this winner’s curse problem, the uninformed agents optimally extract information from prices. Thus they hold the optimal price-contingent portfolio, that is, the portfolio that is mean–variance efficient conditional upon the information revealed by prices.

Because the regressors are the same for each of the six projections, however, SUR boils down to ordinary least squares. 35 The FF benchmark portfolios are identified as holding stock in big , small , high-value , medium-value , or low-value firms . 29 That is, there is little doubt about the significance of the outperformance. This is a (heteroscedasticity-consistent) estimate of the standard deviation of the return differences, under the null that the expected return differences equal 0. Are constants and ” is a local martingale uncorrelated with B.

asset pricing and portfolio choice theory

“Kerry Back offers us a rigorous, but accessible treatment of the asset pricing theory concepts that every doctoral student in finance should learn. A distinguished scholar in the field provides a presentation that is clear yet concise.” This book is a textbook at the Ph.D. or Masters in Quantitative Finance level. It covers single-period, discrete-time, and continuous-time financial models. It provides introductions to many current research topics, and each chapter contains exercises. Further conceptual results include aggregation and mutual fund separation theory, both of which are useful for understanding equilibrium and asset pricing.

Perpetual Options and the Leland Model

No further adjustments were made, although one obviously could think of many potential improvements (iterated least squares, higher-order autocorrelation in the error term, autoregressive heteroscedasticity, etc.). Our theoretical analysis implies that in the partially revealing rational expectations equilibrium, this investment strategy fares better, in mean–variance terms, than indexing. In contrast, if the CAPM holds, then indexing is optimal. Hence, to test the partially revealing rational expectations equilibrium against the CAPM, we compare the performance of the index to that of the price-contingent portfolio strategy of the uninformed agent. This analysis is cast in the context of the simple case characterized in the next corollary. The difference in Sharpe ratios is estimated on the basis of a moving, fixed-length window of sixty months centered around the target month.

In principle, one can construct those portfolios by combining individual stocks. This requires, however, that one handles thousands of different stocks, correlating their returns to their prices, a computationally challenging exercise. A more parsimonious approach is to use groups of stocks as building blocks for our portfolios.

asset pricing and portfolio choice theory

Wang assumes that informed agents observe the stochastically evolving mean of the cash-flow process. Thus, the uninformed agents must continuously learn about this state variable. Hence, to write the equilibrium price as a function of observable variables, one would have to include the entire history of the process. Thus we find that our price-contingent allocation https://forexdelta.net/ strategy significantly outperforms the index. This is consistent with our noisy rational expectations model, where prices reflect economically relevant information, while at the same time not fully revealing all of it. Hence, the performance of price-contingent strategies using only ex ante information to form portfolios of these assets cannot be due to data mining.

Stochastic Discount Factors

Portfolio 2 also selects large companies, but with a medium book to market value. Portfolios 4 to 6 are analogous to Portfolios 1 to 3, but for small firms only. We focus on monthly returns on U.S. common stock listed on the NYSE, AMEX, and NASDAQ, as recorded by CRSP for the period from July 1927 until December 2000.

It arises because the agents with endowment shocks are willing to pay a premium to hedge their risk. Thus, the performance obtained by the uninformed agents reflects the price other agents are willing to pay for insurance. We look at two popular asset pricing models, the CAPM and the APT, as well as complete-markets pricing. In the case of the CAPM, the first-order conditions link nicely to the traditional measures of portfolio performance. 1, the momentum effect is perfectly consistent with our theoretical framework. It is, however, a secondary effect, which means that the momentum strategy should not outperform our price-contingent strategy when evaluated in mean–variance space.

ISE Fundamentals of Corporate Finance

Jimenez Garcia offers an interesting empirical analysis of asset pricing under private information, relying on industry groupings. We assume the informed agents observe a signal on the next cash flow, which is then publicly observed. Investors can perform the projection because they know the parameters of the cash flows, endowment processes, as well as the pricing equation. Another difference is that finite horizon models are nonstationary, while we analyze stationary price equilibrium functions. Cochrane , but we combine the SMB, HML, and momentum strategy with the index, instead of the risk-free asset.

As agents seek to trade away from their undiversified endowments, to hold more balanced portfolios. For example, consider an agent working for Exxon, whose income and wealth are exposed to the risk of this firm and, more generally, to the oil industry. This agent will form his optimal portfolio taking into account his exposure to this firm and industry.

When there is a risk-free asset, x ˜, being spanned by a constant and an excess return, is in the span of the returns and hence must equal m ˜ p . Many finance papers use one or more of the following special utility functions, the first three of which have already been introduced. The lisk tolerance formulas below are all straightforward calculations. Under a supplementary weak completeness assumption, it is shown that the validity of the MFT for general utility functions implies the replicability property for options on the numéraire portfolio described above.

Is a constant and ” is a local martingale uncorrelated with B. Is the positive root of the quadratic equation, and to derive A. Therefore, the intertemporal budget constraint (13.34) holds. By concavity, the first-order condition is sufficient for optimality. ¯ it suffices to sum this over h, noting that aggregate initial wealth is p0 ✓. This exercise is a ver’ simple version of a model of the bid-ask spread presented by Stoll .

The relationship between our price-contingent strategy and size and value investing is less clear, because there is no role for firm size or book value of assets in our theoretical framework. To the extent that size and value are secondary effects, enhancement of indexing by skewing weights toward small firms or high book-to-market value ratios should not lead to outperformance relative to our price-contingent strategy. Because optimal weights for our price-contingent what is fx choice strategy are based on estimated expected returns, variances, and covariances, we inevitably introduce estimation error. When we base ex ante volatility estimates on the covariance matrix of the prediction errors from GLS projections of returns onto prices, we fail to properly account for estimation error. The ex post volatilities can readily be estimated as mean squared differences between returns actually recorded over the target months and ex ante expected returns .

Asset Management

When combining the zero-investment strategies with the risk-free asset only, the combinations generated inferior performance. Thus, our choice to combine with the market index effectively stacks the deck against finding evidence that the price-contingent strategy outperforms strategies based on size, value, or momentum. Are common knowledge to all the agents (see Definition 4, pp. 138 and 139). Hence, in this economy, the aggregate endowment of the risky assets is common knowledge. In the Roll Critique, the econometrician cannot observe the market portfolio.

To offset this increase, 5% of the wealth is invested in Treasury bills. 23 In particular, we determine the right combination of our price-contingent strategy with investment in the market portfolio that generates the same ex post volatility as the index. The left panel shows average momentum returns in excess of average index returns. The right panel displays the average excess returns earned by the price-contingent strategy. One should bear in mind that these restrictions are made only for the sake of simplicity. We checked that in a more complicated model, where uninformed agents could receive endowment shocks, qualitatively similar results obtain.

Signed books

To document this point, we estimated the partial correlation between a portfolio’s return and its own price. Below is a list of the average slope coefficients in the GLS projections of the returns of the six FF benchmark portfolios onto prices. 33 In contrast, it was not numerical differentiation python necessary to include the risk-free asset in the price-contingent strategy to match its volatility with that of the index. Hence, simply adding these zero-investment portfolios to the market would have increased the volatility of the portfolio above that of the index.

Factor Models

We find that the optimal price-contingent portfolio outperforms the index, both economically and statistically. Some investors have private information about the future cash flows, while others are uninformed. Revelation is only partial because the demand of informed investors reflects their random endowment shocks, along with their signals. This pricing relation cannot be directly relied upon in the econometrics since the beliefs of the representative agent are not observable by the econometrician. Hence, to test our model, we instead focus on portfolio choice. We show that portfolio separation does not obtain, as investors hold different portfolios, reflecting their different information sets.

Standard least squares projection coefficients converge faster. A natural choice for these groups of stocks is to focus on the six portfolios that have been used extensively in the empirical asset pricing literature. These are specific portfolios constructed from a double sort of the securities based on the size of the issuing firms, as well as the ratio of book value to market value. We will refer to them as the six Fama-French benchmark portfolios. Portfolio 1 selects stocks of large companies with a low ratio of book to market value.

DeMarzo and Skiadas reflects their assumption that the aggregate supply of each of the risky assets is common knowledge for all the agents. To illustrate our theoretical findings, we perform a numerical analysis and simulation of the equilibrium price dynamics. This exercise highlights the implementability of our noisy rational expectations analytic framework and illustrates how momentum effects can arise in equilibrium. Which is independent of c and hence maximized by any 0  c  w. This exercise illustrates the fact that the transversality condition (9.25) holds in bounded and negative dynamic programming. This exercise repeats the previous one, but using asset payo↵s and prices instead of returns and solving for the optimal number of shares to hold of each asset instead of the optimal amount to invest.

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *